Shephard's lemma is a major result in microeconomics having applications in the theory of the firm and in consumer choice. The lemma states that if indifference curves of the expenditure or cost function are convex, then the cost minimizing point of a given good () with price is unique. The idea is that a consumer will buy a unique ideal amount of each item to minimize the price for obtaining a certain level of utility given the price of goods in the market.
The lemma is named after Ronald Shephard who gave a proof using the distance formula in his book Theory of Cost and Production Functions (Princeton University Press, 1953). The equivalent result in the context of consumer theory was first derived by Lionel W. McKenzie in 1957. It states that the partial derivatives of the expenditure function with respect to the prices of goods equal the Hicksian demand functions for the relevant goods. Similar results had already been derived by John Hicks (1939) and Paul Samuelson (1947).
In consumer theory, Shephard's lemma states that the demand for a particular good for a given level of utility and given prices , equals the derivative of the expenditure function with respect to the price of the relevant good:
where is the Hicksian demand for good , is the expenditure function, and both functions are in terms of prices (a vector ) and utility .
Likewise, in the theory of the firm, the lemma gives a similar formulation for the conditional factor demand for each input factor: the derivative of the cost function with respect to the factor price:
where is the conditional factor demand for input , is the cost function, and both functions are in terms of factor prices (a vector ) and output .
Although Shephard's original proof used the distance formula, modern proofs of the Shephard's lemma use the envelope theorem.
The proof is stated for the two-good case for ease of notation. The expenditure function is the value function of the constrained optimization problem characterized by the following Lagrangian:
By the envelope theorem the derivatives of the value function with respect to the parameter are:
where is the minimizer (i.
This page is automatically generated and may contain information that is not correct, complete, up-to-date, or relevant to your search query. The same applies to every other page on this website. Please make sure to verify the information with EPFL's official sources.
NOTOC In economics, a consumer's indirect utility function gives the consumer's maximal attainable utility when faced with a vector of goods prices and an amount of income . It reflects both the consumer's preferences and market conditions. This function is called indirect because consumers usually think about their preferences in terms of what they consume rather than prices.
The Slutsky equation (or Slutsky identity) in economics, named after Eugen Slutsky, relates changes in Marshallian (uncompensated) demand to changes in Hicksian (compensated) demand, which is known as such since it compensates to maintain a fixed level of utility. There are two parts of the Slutsky equation, namely the substitution effect, and income effect. In general, the substitution effect can be negative for consumers as it can limit choices. He designed this formula to explore a consumer's response as the price changes.