Capital intensity is the amount of fixed or real capital present in relation to other factors of production, especially labor. At the level of either a production process or the aggregate economy, it may be estimated by the capital to labor ratio, such as from the points along a capital/labor isoquant.
The use of tools and machinery makes labor more effective, so rising capital intensity (or "capital deepening") pushes up the productivity of labor. Capital intensive societies tend to have a higher standard of living over the long run.
Calculations made by Robert Solow claimed that economic growth was mainly driven by technological progress (productivity growth) rather than inputs of capital and labor. However recent economic research has invalidated that theory, since Solow did not properly consider changes in both investment and labor inputs.
Dale Jorgenson, of Harvard University, President of the American Economic Association in 2000, concludes that: 'Griliches and I showed that changes in the quality of capital and labor inputs and the quality of investment goods explained most of the Solow residual. We estimated that capital and labor inputs accounted for 85 percent of growth during the period 1945–1965, while only 15 percent could be attributed to productivity growth... This has precipitated the sudden obsolescence of earlier productivity research employing the conventions of Kuznets and Solow.'
John Ross has analysed the long term correlation between the level of investment in the economy, rising from 5-7% of GDP at the time of the Industrial Revolution in England, to 25% of GDP in the post-war German 'economic miracle', to over 35% of GDP in the world's most rapidly growing contemporary economies of India and China.
Taking the G7 and other largest economies, Jorgenson and Vu conclude: 'the growth of world output between input growth and productivity... input growth greatly predominated... Productivity growth accounted for only one-fifth of the total during 1989-1995, while input growth accounted for almost four-fifths.
Cette page est générée automatiquement et peut contenir des informations qui ne sont pas correctes, complètes, à jour ou pertinentes par rapport à votre recherche. Il en va de même pour toutes les autres pages de ce site. Veillez à vérifier les informations auprès des sources officielles de l'EPFL.
'Preparing for the apocalypse' takes you to Puglia, where people are confronted with millions of century-old olive trees dying.
In dialogue with local communities, we will explore whether architecture
'Preparing for the apocalypse' takes you to Puglia, where people are confronted with millions of century-old olive trees dying.
In dialogue with local communities, we will explore whether architecture
In energy policy, energy efficiency constitutes a central element in reducing domestic and, specifically, industrial en-ergy use. Unfortunately, the effectiveness of energy efficiency improvements in achieving its targets is known to be limited by rebound ...
Le modèle de Solow est un des principaux modèles de la théorie de la croissance économique. Développé indépendamment par Robert Solow et Trevor Swan en 1956, il est un modèle de l'économie néoclassique. Le modèle de Solow vise à expliquer la croissance économique grâce à ses déterminants que sont l'accumulation du capital et le facteur travail. Le modèle s'appuie sur deux courbes majeures : celle de l'augmentation de l'épargne, et donc du capital, et celle de la dépréciation du capital.
vignette|Une illustration commentée de l'exemple du détour de production selon Böhm-Bawerk Le détour de production est un concept d'économie qui désigne la nécessité pour un producteur, paradoxale mais efficace, de faire un détour dans sa production pour être capable ultérieurement de produire plus, plus vite et mieux. Le détour de production conduit à réaliser un investissement, qui s'illustre par un allongement du processus de production (étapes).
La controverse des deux Cambridge est un débat économique sur la nature, le rôle et la quantification des biens d'équipement, c'est-à-dire des moyens de production. Ayant eu lieu dans les années 1960, elle doit son nom aux villes où enseignaient les protagonistes du débat : Cambridge en Angleterre (université de Cambridge) et Cambridge aux États-Unis (Massachusetts Institute of Technology).
Atmospheric new particle formation (NPF) is an important source of climate-relevant aerosol particles which has been observed at many locations globally. To study this phenomenon, the first step is to identify whether an NPF event occurs or not on a given ...
This thesis aims to provide novel analyses and data that improve the understanding of the financing of investments in clean technologies. In particular, this thesis explores the role that private and public actors play in supporting young innovative firms. ...