Constant elasticity of substitution (CES), in economics, is a property of some production functions and utility functions. Several economists have featured in the topic and have contributed in the final finding of the constant. They include Tom McKenzie, John Hicks and Joan Robinson. The vital economic element of the measure is that it provided the producer a clear picture of how to move between different modes or types of production.
Specifically, it arises in a particular type of aggregator function which combines two or more types of consumption goods, or two or more types of production inputs into an aggregate quantity. This aggregator function exhibits constant elasticity of substitution.
Despite having several factors of production in substitutability, the most common are the forms of elasticity of substitution. On the contrary of restricting direct empirical evaluation, the constant Elasticity of Substitution are simple to use and hence are widely used. McFadden states that; The constant E.S assumption is a restriction on the form of production possibilities, and one can characterize the class of production functions which have this property. This has been done by Arrow-Chenery-Minhas-Solow for the two-factor production case. The CES production function is a neoclassical production function that displays constant elasticity of substitution. In other words, the production technology has a constant percentage change in factor (e.g. labour and capital) proportions due to a percentage change in marginal rate of technical substitution. The two factor (capital, labor) CES production function introduced by Solow, and later made popular by Arrow, Chenery, Minhas, and Solow is:
where
= Quantity of output
= Factor productivity
= Share parameter
= Quantities of primary production factors (Capital and Labor)
= = Substitution parameter
= = Elasticity of substitution
= degree of homogeneity of the production function. Where = 1 (Constant return to scale), < 1 (Decreasing return to scale), > 1 (Increasing return to scale).
This page is automatically generated and may contain information that is not correct, complete, up-to-date, or relevant to your search query. The same applies to every other page on this website. Please make sure to verify the information with EPFL's official sources.
As a topic of economics, utility is used to model worth or value. Its usage has evolved significantly over time. The term was introduced initially as a measure of pleasure or happiness as part of the theory of utilitarianism by moral philosophers such as Jeremy Bentham and John Stuart Mill. The term has been adapted and reapplied within neoclassical economics, which dominates modern economic theory, as a utility function that represents a consumer's ordinal preferences over a choice set, but is not necessarily comparable across consumers or possessing a cardinal interpretation.
This course provides students with a working knowledge of macroeconomic models that explicitly incorporate financial markets. The goal is to develop a broad and analytical framework for analyzing the
À l’heure où la Bigness tokyoïte s’empare de la petite échelle et de toutes les potentialités qui lui sont rattachées, ce projet propose une solution de renouvellement urbain durable pour le quartier de Yanaka. Ayant largement survécu aux destructions mass ...
2023
,
Quels sont les projets de nos aînés? Quels sont leurs rêves? A un certain âge, il semble que ces questions n'ont plus le droit d'être posées. Pourtant, il n'y a pas de limite d'âge à se projeter, à se réinventer. Nous oublions bien trop souvent que le troi ...
« Urbanculture » est une méthode. Le projet confronte pensée rationnelle et notions de confort et d’atmosphère à partir d’une idée de « pré-image » comme expression de l’articulation entre la construction d’une image et l’image de sa construction. Il suggè ...